|
|
|
The Formation of the Modern East Asian Economy
They thus
decreed artificial values, restricted usages, and issued
different qualities of copper coin, all under the recurring
illusion that the Chinese court could dictate to the rest
of the empire and even East Asia the market value of their
coin. When reality, as it inevitably did, broke through
the imperial gates, they sought a variety of solutions
to this persistent problem.
First, we can mention the
easiest solution, that of debasement. From the seventh
century up to the early twelfth century, the feature of
Chinese currency which helped assure its use throughout
East and southeast Asia up to the last century was its
reasonably stable copper content. During the peak years
of mintage in the late eleventh century, government coins
usually contained 65% copper, 25% lead, and 10% tin. From
the 1130s to the 1270s, however, a severe military and
financial crisis hit the Chinese government thanks to
the Jurchen conquest of north China. Consequently, it
felt compelled to debase the metal contents of its new
issues of copper coins. In them lead counted for 50 to
60 %, copper just 40%, and tin 5%. Over time, this practice
only invited widespread hoarding of good coin and the
counterfeiting of even worse coins. And when fifteenth
and sixteenth century Chinese emperors issued better coins,
it only confirmed Gresham's law that "bad coin drives
out good." Overall, then, the twelfth to the seventeenth
century saw a significant decline in the quality of Chinese
copper coins and thus a far less welcome in China and
the rest of Asia for these new coins than for the old
Tang and Sung coins.
The solution to copper
shortage most favoured by Chinese governments from roughly
1100 to 1450 was the issuance of paper money. Paper government
notes had been used in western China since the 1020s,
and bills of exchange had been commonly used even earlier
by merchants to transfer funds from city to city. But
in 1160, the Southern Sung government's introduction of
new convertible paper money for the more economically
advanced areas of south China was coupled with its preference
for this paper money over silver and gold in many of the
same areas. Then, from 1173 it registered its official
income and expenditures half in this paper money and half
in copper cash, a policy which only spurred on the hoarding
and leakage abroad of copper cash. Remarkably, these paper
notes retained their value in private transactions right
up to the 1190s, as the government's new monetary system
linked the value of the issued paper currency to its stock
of precious metals, some 20 million strings of copper
cash. But, from the early thirteenth century, soaring
military expenses pressured the government into issuing
12 times more paper money than this storehold figure.
1|2|3|4|5|6|7|8|9|10|Next
|
| Sponsored by the Chuan Lyu Foundation © 1997 - 2008 The Chuan Lyu Foundation All Rights Reserved | |
|