|
|
|
The Formation of the Modern East Asian Economy
The figures even worsened
over the remaining decades of Southern Sung rule in the
thirteenth century. But this experience, along with even
worse policy mishaps in North China under the foreign
Jurchen government, did little to persuade the Yuan dynasty
from attempting to establish its own paper notes as the
sole currency in China from 1260. At the start, even though
this Mongol government in north China banned the use of
metal coins in tax payments and private trading, it declared
its notes fully convertible to silver. By the late 1270s
it had, at least implicitly, withdrawn from this principle.
In 1287, it devalued its 1260 notes by 80% and issued
new, unconvertible notes. Yet, paper money remained the
principal means of exchange at least until 1350, when
the depreciation reached such astronomic levels that trade
outside of its capital, present-day Beijing, was conducted
solely by barter.
This unhappy experience
was essentially repeated over the first seven decades
of the subsequent Ming dynasty from 1368 to 1435. The
first emperor of this dynasty sought to bully his way
through the problem of copper shortage. An infamous xenophobe
and monomaniac, he regarded coinage more as a political
pawn than an economic factor. Oblivious like many of his
advisers of the intrinsic value of coinage, he had ultimate
faith in his state's ability to set the value of money
and run a highly self-enclosed economy. In the last quarter
of the fourteenth century, he closed down the country's
silver mines prohibited the use of its own coin in trade,
outlawed the export of gold silver, and copper coins,
banned all privately conducted foreign trade, and issued
an excessive amount of non-convertible paper notes. By
his death in 1398, this policy had set back the commercial
development of the country, particularly in the south.
Even if most commercial transactions were in its paper
money and the government issued at least four bans on
the use of silver, by the 1430s, the dynasty's notes were
worth, in silver, less than 1% of their marked value.
Recognizing the impact of this deterioration not least
on its own tax revenues, the Chinese government allowed
its experiments with paper money to come to an inglorious
end. Not until the nineteenth century would it return
to paper money.
Out of this series of failures
emerged a third solution, which gained increasing prominence
from the mid-fifteenth to the seventeenth centuries: that
is, the mining and usage of greater amounts of other metals,
especially silver. In the ninth century and earlier, silver
had already found many uses in China, from art works to
gambling and, of course, bribery. As such, it was employed
largely by the wealthy. Yet, from the early tenth century,
silver ingots received wider and greater use (as did gold).
1|2|3|4|5|6|7|8|9|10|Next
|
| Sponsored by the Chuan Lyu Foundation © 1997 - 2008 The Chuan Lyu Foundation All Rights Reserved | |
|