The Formation of the Modern East Asian Economy
In
addition, the silver shortage worsened seriously. Between
1827 and 1849, as much as 134 million Spanish dollars
left China due, possibly, opium imports. This outflow
of silver only intensified the silver shortage and prompted
widespread deflation, depression, and bankruptcy. In
1838, Li Zexu reported that sales in such commercial
centers as Nanhao in Suzhou and Hankow in Hubei had
dropped by half compared with two or three decades earlier.
At mid-century Feng Guifen would write, "All great and
wealthy merchants have gone bankrupt, and business of
all kinds have decreased by 50 to 60%." And, as is well
known, the rise in the price of silver, particularly
in relation to copper cash, in effect obliged small
landowners to pay more taxes. In the second half of
the nineteenth century, silver began to flow back into
the country. But that brought little relief. After 1875,
international silver prices began to decline, and by
1897 had lost more than half its value vis-à-vis gold.
For 90% of the countries in the world, this change brought
little trouble, as they were on the gold standard. In
China, still on the silver standard and anxious to pay
more for silver than other nations, this addiction to
silver continued. Thus, when in 1897 Japan converted
to the gold standard, it was surprised to recover only
a tenth of the silver yen dollars it had issued between
1870 and 1897. Most of the rest of these coins had ended
up in India, the Straits, and elsewhere in southeast
Asia to be melted down into ornaments or demonetized
by Chinese. Meanwhile, from the 1880s, Chinese provincial
mints increasingly issued debased coins.
It is not surprising,
then, that Japan and even China turned to Western banks
and other institutions for capital to fund their debts,
wars, and industrial efforts. If Western traders were
still stymied in gaining control of the coastal trade,
if they still failed to penetrate the interior trade
of East Asian countries, then nonetheless had the capital
that had once flowed so readily from Japan and Mexico
to China.
Five weeks ago, I began
this series of lectures in eleventh century China, with
the intention of demonstrating how the separate economies
of East Asia were increasingly interlocked with one
another over the next nine centuries. This interlocking
was obviously centered on China, but for it to succeed,
China had to look elsewhere. Fortunately, it found the
necessary goods and markets in Japan, Mexico, Southeast
Asia, and India. These countries did not at all times
maintain their participation. Like Japan they might
retreat into an import substitution policy or pursue
domestic agricultural development at the expense of
greater ties with their neighbors. Secondly, the expansion
of the Chinese economy overseas was aided by the great
number of Chinese junks, estimated by Du Li for the
China coast trade at 220,000 in the early nineteenth
century.
Previous |59|60|61|62|63|64|65|66|67|68
|